Can the European Central Bank (ECB) go broke?
Summary:
We studied the balance sheet of the ECB and its evolution and analysed the growth of its main components on the assets and liabilities sides. We show that although non-conventional policies like QE mechanically creates base money and generates seigniorage profits, they have a relatively small effect on inflation and a slightly higher effect on inflation expectation and on the Euro currency exchange rate. We concluded that uncontrolled QE including debt cancellation would put the ECB at risk of losing its credibility, even if it cannot technically go broke.
Introduction
The outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic has generated a widespread and simultaneous shock on supply and demand across the world, with a severe impact on GDP growth. This “black swan scenario1” has forced central banks and governments to move swiftly against the risk of a repeat of the great depression. Government spending was increased in order to maintain the productive capacity of the economy, with massive programs helping firms to partially compensate the income losses experienced by their furloughed workers, and government guarantees to preserve their access to credit. With European countries facing large amounts of government debt and an increasing public debt to GDP ratio, the ECB (European Central Bank) hasstated that it would be ready to increase its asset purchases (known as Quantitative Easing, or Q.E) and therefore to monetize deficits. Debt cancellation scenarios, which go a step further, are now being pushed forward by a minority of radical outsiders in the name of Modern monetary theory (MMT). Even if the balance sheet of a central bank often does not
necessarily portray its success, as it does not have the liquidity constraint faced by governments and commercial banks, its financial strength can often reinforce its own credibility. This project will discuss the role of the ECB, the implementation of its non-conventional monetary policy, and also the risks it is currently facing in the midst of a deep worldwide economic recession.
1. What is a Central Bank and why does it exist?
Historically, central banks have often been better understood by their functions rather than their objectives. Central banks were generally the dominant issuers of banknotes, which in turn usually gave them sufficient scale to be the preferred choice for government banking, and this scale also provided the ability for a fraction of the issuance to be handed back to government (“seigniorage”).
Many central banks were founded in times of economic turmoil, in an effort to restore price stability and the credibility of banknotes after times of over issuance. In more modern times, the dominant bank would often be a lender to customer banks in times of liquidity shortage and became a “lender of last resort”. This was because it was in their commercial interest to do so, and the central bank could not be declared bankrupt or have negative capital as it could use its money creation toolkit to pay off its own debt.
Overall, the Central bank acts as a “Bank of banks” with a mandate to warrant monetary stability by controlled inflation (around 2% for the ECB yearly), and also to promote economic growth in the country (or countries) using its currency. Though many central banks such as the Federal Reserve (Fed) or the Bank of England (BoE) have this dual mandate, the ECB has a single mandate focused on inflation and financial stability.
2. The Balance sheet of the ECB
The consolidated balance sheet of the Euro area represents the ECB and the 27 NCBs (National Central Banks) inside the Eurosystem. How does a Central Bank’s balance sheet work? It looks like the balance sheet of a commercial bank, but with a huge difference: a central bank can create its own liabilities, issuing its own currency. Hence the equivalent of its shareholder’s equity is somewhat conventional. In a paper from 20082, William BUITER has proposed a stylised view of a balance sheet.
At the top of the table are the liabilities and the shareholder equity (the ECB’s “net worth” or capital). Firstly, the monetary liabilities (M in table), sometimes called base money, is the sum of currency in circulation and balances or reserves held with the central banks by commercial banks. The central bank also has non-monetary liabilities (O in table) which can be debt to the government, the domestic private sector, or to international organisations like the IMF. The bottom of the table shows the assets of the central bank: the central bank owns securities (D), which are treasury bills and government or corporate bonds, private debt (L), which are loans to the private sector (essentially banks), and official
foreign exchange and gold reserves (R). The “conventional” equity of the central bank (W) is determined as the value of assets minus the value of liabilities.
In short, W = D + L+ R - M -O
A simplified view of the evolution of the balance sheet of the ECB is presented in the table below. We have adapted the framework initially set out by W.BUITER.
From the table above, we can see that the ECB balance sheet has quintupled since the end of 2006. The total value of assets of the ECB has gone from 1.2 to 5.3 Trillion Euros. Since the beginning of the great financial crisis in August 2007, the Central Banks of G4 countries have expanded at a high pace, which is reflected in the graph below.
Asset side of the ECB’s balance sheet: securities and long-term lending
As regards to the component of the balance sheet, the most obvious change on its assets side is the emergence of long-term lending to credit institutions within the Euro zone, but also the vast increase in the amount of securities owned by the bank. Monetary policy has evolved and new instruments, such as TLTROS (Targeted Long-Term Lending Operations) and APPs (Asset Purchasing Program), are now part of the ECB’s quantitative easing (QE) toolkit: their main purpose is to provide monetary accommodation. In times of crises, TLTROS operations provides long-term funding through cheap liquidity – currently with negative interest rates of -1% - provided by the central bank to commercial banks, to ensure cheap credit is available (and distributed) for individuals and corporates. This reduces the cost of funding of the commercial banks, which is especially useful in times of crisis. It also increases liquidity in markets and base money (M). In light of recent events, the ECB has created an asset purchasing program called the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Program (PEPP), which aims to stabilise the securities markets and to contain disinflationary pressures, according to Philip Lane, by lowering levels of commercial and corporate debt and meet their demand for liquidity to maintain cash flow. Latest numbers indicate that the ECB has bought more than 3.3 Trillion euros worth of securities through its asset purchasing programs, that include government debt as well as corporate debt. The large increase in Gold and forex reserves on the Asset side between 2006 and 2020, going from 321 to 958 Billion, reflect large surpluses in the balance of payments of the Eurozone, which is a sign of strength of the currency, as there is less demand for Euro creation.
Liabilities side of the ECB’s balance sheet: QE and base money creation
On the liabilities side of the balance sheet, reserve balances have gone from 177 Billion euros to 2.3 Trillion euros between 2006 and 2020. Central Bank base money (M) has been created through the process of buying securities owned by non-financial institutions. The large growth on the asset side of the balance sheet is reflected on the liabilities side, and this expansion shows the money creation effect of non-conventional policies such as Quantitative Easing. Most Central banks are often reluctant to talk about the liabilitiesside of the balance sheet and often insist on the portfolio rebalancing effect on the asset side. Asset purchases by the Central bank from non-bank investors create base money (M), while purchases from commercial banks do not.
• The impact of QE on base money:
⮚ Asset purchases from non-bank investors:
Asset purchases made by the Central Bank from non-bank investors(non-financial entities like pension funds or governments) create Central bank base money. This policy is usually called Quantitative Easing (QE). The main mechanism for money creation is shown in the T-accounts below: the liabilities of all three bodies are represented on the right-hand side of the table, and their asset side is on the left-hand side. Firstly, the central bank buys bonds from the private investors through their commercial bank and sends money to them: the private investors have less bonds and more deposits on its asset side, whilst the central bank has more bonds on its asset side. More money therefore appears on the deposit account of the private investors, on the liabilities side of the commercial bank: this means base money has been created. More reserves also appear on the asset side of the commercial bank and the liabilities side of the Central bank. We can see that the process occurred entirely at the initiative of the Central Bank, and the commercial bank had to create more deposits and was “forced” to create more reserves consequently. The same conclusion is valid when the central bank accepts to finance fiscal deficits, whether or not the bonds are purchased on the primary market.
⮚ Asset purchases from Banks
The main difference when the assets are purchased from commercial banks is that the balance sheet of the commercial banks remain unchanged. The bond asset formerly owned by the commercial bank is transferred to the central bank, and consequently is replaced by new reserves on the commercial bank asset side. The following chart sketches QE flows when assets are purchased from commercial banks:
Increasing conventional equity in the ECB’s balance sheet:
Between 2006 and 2020, the conventional equity in the ECB’s balance sheet grew from 64 Billion (5.6%) to 616 Billion euros (10.9%). This larger equity share, which is a rough indicator of the bank’s solvency,suggests that the structure of the ECB’s balance sheet has grown stronger during this period. This is a direct consequence of the benefits of seigniorage, which we discuss in the next section.
3. Opportunities and risks of a rapid expansion of the ECBs balance sheet:
Seigniorage is at the heart of balance sheet expansion. The creation of base money by the central bank is virtually costless, and with this money it can buy assets that generate revenue. The spread between the cost of its assets and the cost of its liabilities generate a profit for the central bank, which is named seigniorage, which references profits from money creation made by lords (“seigneurs” in French) during medieval times. In countries with National central banks, including the euro area, most of these central bank profits are distributed to national treasuries. In the case of the ECB, seigniorage profits from quantitative easing are redistributed to treasuries of European governments. It should however be noted, as mentioned by the BIS5, that central banks pursue national welfare rather than profits. Central banks are not investment funds, and their gains and losses belong to society.
A strong balance sheet also contributes to the credibility of the central bank. Conversely, a weak balance sheet of National Central banks have historically been the hallmark for external crises in emerging countries. For instance, when foreign exchange and gold reserves reach a low point because of external imbalances, the central bank cannot guarantee the convertibility of the currency. At the end of the process, the IMF may be needed to recapitalise the central bank. This is far from being the context of the eurozone, partially because the euro is already a reserve currency (forming around 25% of all central bank foreign currency assets).
Many risks are associated to a rapid expansion of a Central bank balance sheet. Hence, like many central banks, the ECB is aiming for a possible normalization of its balance sheet once the economic storm, requiring massive intervention of central banks, is over. We can identify three main risks of qualitative easing policies: a massive credit risk for the central bank, the resumption of inflation above its yearly target, and a risk to the status of the Euro currency.
Firstly, a credit risk arises from the securities portfolio owned by the ECB. One should be reminded of the tensions that erupted when the ECB bought Greek government bonds in 2011, and when it massively increased its holdings of Italian and Spanish government debt in order to provide them with a backstop needed to defend the Euro currency (Mario Draghi’s phrase of “Whatever it takes” in 2012). This risk has increased dramatically with the corporate sector purchasing program (CSPP), where the ECB is exposed to the risk of default of private sector entities.
Secondly, inflationary pressures are often associated with the expansion of base money. We studied the statistical relationship between a) the size of the ECB’s balance sheet as a percentage of GDP and b) core inflation/inflation expectations in the Eurozone. Long term data does not suggest that there is a strong correlation between the balance sheet and core inflation indicators.
However, the correlation between the size of the ECB’s balance sheet and inflation expectations (5- year inflation in 5 years) is slightly more significant. What seems troubling is that despite this massive expansion, inflation expectations remain well below the 2% inflation target set out by the ECB. It is therefore not clear that QE generates inflation.
Lastly, as shown in Graph 4 below, there is a more significant impact of the ECB’s balance sheet expansion on the exchange rate of the Euro against the US dollar. Between 2014 and early 2020, the balance sheet of the ECB has continued to grow and European interest rates have shrunk to very low or even negative levels, while the FED started to taper its balance sheet. The Covid-19 pandemic has brutally interrupted this long-term trend.
Conclusion: QE as the ECB’s method of maintaining financial stability in the Eurozone without losing its credibility.
In this research project we studied the balance sheet of the ECB and its massive expansion since the great Financial crisis, and the ECB’s use of APPs through non-conventional monetary policy like quantitative easing. We checked the impact of balance sheet expansion on core inflation indicators, inflation expectations and the level of the Euro currency. We concluded that lower interest rates and the ECB’s use of non-conventional policies (increasing base money in the economy) did not have much of an effect on inflation, but there were bigger correlations with inflation expectations and the Euro Dollar exchange rate. They have also been efficient tools to reduce the level of financial tensions (or the level of systemic stress6) recently. This may lead to the wrong conclusions: if printing money is free for the ECB, coming together with the full benefits of seigniorage, why not cancel the government debt owned by the ECB, as suggested by MMT economists?
Paying attention to the structure of the balance sheet gives an inkling of the risks attached to such an option. Our research shows that this would more than likely to result in central bank technical insolvency (negative equity) and uncontrollable deficit, causing massive debasement of the Euro currency, calling off de facto any future QE program and resulting altogether in a loss of credibility, with potentially an inflation spiral at the end point. The use of “Helicopter money” would be a bridge too far that would put the European project at risk. Through policies of Quantitative easing, the ECB can provide an easing of financial conditions and ensure that the economic downturn is not made worse by a credit squeeze, and also achieve its single mandate of keeping a low yearly inflation rate. Overall, the ECB cannot technically go broke but can severely damage its credibility if it loses control of inflation and its own currency, the Euro.
References
1. N.TALEB, “The black swan: the impact of the highly improbable”, 2007.
2 Buiter, Willem, Can Central Banks go broke? CEPR Policy insight No.24, May 2008.
3. Courtesy of Jean Pierre Landau, former Vice-Governor of the Banque de France
4 HSBC global research, 29 June 2020. US bonds- the QE quandary. Three common misconceptions
5 Bank for International Settlements (BIS Paper n71) – Central Bank Finances – David Archer and Paul Moser Boehn (April 2013) – The diagram above is extracted from the same paper.
6 See Philip Lane’s blog on the ECB website dated 22 June 2020.